Stay up to date with notifications from The Independent

Notifications can be managed in browser preferences.

Why are central bankers trying to increase inflation?

Those who recall double-digit price rises and interest rates struggle to see the problems deflation can bring

Hamish McRae
Saturday 05 March 2016 22:04 GMT
Comments
The headquarters of the European Central Bank in Frankfurt, Germany
The headquarters of the European Central Bank in Frankfurt, Germany (Getty)

Your support helps us to tell the story

From reproductive rights to climate change to Big Tech, The Independent is on the ground when the story is developing. Whether it's investigating the financials of Elon Musk's pro-Trump PAC or producing our latest documentary, 'The A Word', which shines a light on the American women fighting for reproductive rights, we know how important it is to parse out the facts from the messaging.

At such a critical moment in US history, we need reporters on the ground. Your donation allows us to keep sending journalists to speak to both sides of the story.

The Independent is trusted by Americans across the entire political spectrum. And unlike many other quality news outlets, we choose not to lock Americans out of our reporting and analysis with paywalls. We believe quality journalism should be available to everyone, paid for by those who can afford it.

Your support makes all the difference.

For anyone who can remember the 1970s and 1980s it should seem bizarre that central banks should be fighting to create inflation. In 1975, the worst year, the retail price index rose by 24.9 per cent, and while it fell back a bit through the 1980s, in 1990 it was back up at 9.3 per cent. It was a world where some people tried to renegotiate their pay every three months, and where a 10-year fixed rate mortgage in 1981 cost 18 per cent.

Yet this Thursday the European Central Bank is expected to bring in some sort of stimulus partly to boost prices, for inflation in the eurozone fell to minus 0.2 per cent last month, and partly to jack up some growth. Since the ECB deposit rate – the rate it pays to banks to hold money with it – is already minus 0.3 per cent, it faces a conundrum. If a negative rate has failed to generate inflation, would making it yet more negative do the trick? Might it actually make matters worse? The idea is to get banks to lend the money instead of leaving it with the ECB. But since the banks cannot impose a negative rate on depositors (one or two have tried) it just squeezes their profitability and may make them even more cautious. When the Bank of Japan unexpectedly introduced negative rates last month the markets, far from welcoming the move as a way of boosting confidence, plunged.

There are two ways of looking at this. One is to say, well if the policy is not working, we need to fine-tune it to make it more effective, and have governments take additional measures, such as investing in infrastructure, to generate more economic growth. That is the mainstream response and we are going to hear a lot more of it in the coming weeks. Mercifully, we are not quite in this position in the UK or indeed the United States, for there has been a decent economic recovery in both countries (though the latest data here are a bit worrying), and there is some underlying inflation at a consumer level. Expect the recent fall of the pound against the dollar to push up prices a bit more. Still, concerns about deflation both here and in the US do linger.

The other way of looking at this period of zero, near-zero, or even slightly negative inflation is to ask whether it matters. Would a world of stable prices be such a bad thing? The current view that there should be some inflation – around 2 per cent – is a new idea. Targets for inflation only came in as a result of the searing experience of the 1970s and 1980s, when the central banks had lost control and the fabric of our societies was threatened. For long periods in the past, including periods of solid growth, there was no overall change in price levels. People did enjoy an increase in their living standards, but these came through as much from lower prices as from higher incomes. Indeed, you can argue that it is fairer for society to get the benefits of growth through lower prices, because everyone shares in that. If the benefits come in higher wages, the unwaged lose out.

You can catch a glimpse of the way falling prices benefit everyone by what has happened in information technology. It is not just that the price of a mobile phone has fallen as its competence has increased. Many of the apps you “buy” to use on that phone are free. In that particular segment of the world economy, deflation is extreme. If you adjust for quality, prices fall relentlessly year after year. Yet no one worries about that; in fact most of us welcome it. So, why should we worry about the very small declines that have come through in consumer prices in recent months?

I think the answer is that the most recent period of sustained deflation, the 1930s, was a time of profound economic disruption and distress. That shadow hangs over our policy-makers, as indeed it should. But you can argue, I think persuasively, that deflation then was more the result of the disruption than the cause of it. In any case, there is another period when the long-term trend of prices was downwards which saw huge economic progress worldwide. It was the last great burst of globalisation that took place from the 1820s through to 1914.

We know a lot about it. We know that prices in the UK on the eve of the First World War were roughly the same as they had been 100 years earlier, though of course the goods and services available were vastly different. We know there were huge disruptive swings in the business cycle. We know about the misery of working conditions, and we know, looking around the world, of the exploitation by the European empires. But – and this is the big point – overall living standards in the developed world rose at a rate that had never happened before.

To say all this is not to welcome deflation now. It is just to say that we are too frightened of it, and the cure – ultra-low interest rates – may be worse than the disease.

Join our commenting forum

Join thought-provoking conversations, follow other Independent readers and see their replies

Comments

Thank you for registering

Please refresh the page or navigate to another page on the site to be automatically logged inPlease refresh your browser to be logged in